Law in Contemporary Society

View   r14  >  r13  ...
SaswatMisraFirstPaper 14 - 13 Jun 2010 - Main.SaswatMisra
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="FirstPaper"
Changed:
<
<
Update (5/23) - I'm currently working on revising this paper.
>
>
Update (*6/12/10*) - I'm currently working on revising this paper.
 
Changed:
<
<
Relevant Version History:
>
>
Major Version History:
 Version 11 - My first paper

Version 12 - My first paper with Eben's comments

Changed:
<
<
Version 13 - My revised first paper (**currently in progress**)
>
>
Version 13 - Outline for my revised first paper

Version 14 - Working draft of my revised first paper (*in progress*)

 
Changed:
<
<

Finding a Sweet Spot in Private IP Rights

>
>

Finding the Sweet Spot in Private IP Rights

I. Introduction

Government can improve social welfare by implementing policy that encourages technical innovation. While most parties agree that private intellectual property (IP) rights (or their equivalent incentives) are a necessary part of such a policy, the exact “nature” and “degree” of such rights has proven to be highly contentious [1], [2], [3]. The balance between private and public IP rights is almost universally acknowledged to be sub-optimal, but change is hard to come by, as today’s “patent culture” is deeply embedded in United States statues and the day-to-day operation of the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO). Therefore, most proposals to improve the balance between public and private IP rights focus only on small-scale changes.

This essay argues that patent rights should be recognized only for “platform” technology, and not for mere “incremental” innovation, and further, that this revised definition of patentability can be implemented using the current machinery of current patent law under 35 U.S.C. § 103 [4]. Although the proposed policy would dramatically reduce the overall amount of private IP rights awarded to citizens and organizations for their inventions, it would likely encourage the actual kinds of innovation that increases societal welfare, while also avoiding many of the negative side effects of the current patent system.

II. Private IP Rights and Technical Innovation

 
Changed:
<
<
Summary of Thesis:
>
>
Private IP rights create a strong monetary incentive for people and corporations to develop new technology, which, if brought to market, can greatly increase social welfare. However, private IP rights also give rise to many undesirable effects. First, private rights prevent the public from gaining quick and cheap access to patented inventions, including invention that would have been created even without any private IP rights whatsoever. Second, private IP rights tend to concentrate research and development efforts on technologies that are “protectable” and that can be commercialized, rather than those that have the most potential to increase social welfare To avoid these pitfalls, a technology policy should to be carefully crafted to find the “sweet spot” in private IP rights. That is, the best policy is one that creates sufficient inventive incentive, while not unduly robbing the citizenry of quick and cheap access to new innovations, and while encouraging the types of innovation that are most useful to the societal welfare.
 
Deleted:
<
<
(1) - The current patent system fails to strike the right balance between private and public intellectual rights, and therefore fails to properly disseminate technical innovation so as to increase social welfare
 
Changed:
<
<
(2) - A better balance could be reached if the patent system distinguished between "platform" technology, which should be patentable (and subject to mandatory "takings" with just compensation by the gov't) and "incremental" innovation, which should not be patentable
>
>

III. The Current Patent System Misses the Sweet Spot

 
Changed:
<
<
(3) - The current patent system can implement the proposed policy change through the Section 103 "non-obviousness" requirement for patentability (while a ground-up solution would obviously be more desirable, it is less realistic)
>
>
Unfortunately, the current patent system fails to find the sweet spot in private IP rights. First, the current system makes no effort recognize, and deny patentability to, technologies that would have been brought to bear even without private IP rights, thereby increasing the cost of these goods to the public. Second, the current system diverts research and development resources from long-term and potentially ground-breaking, but unpatentable, innovations to short-term ideas that are only incrementally innovation, but that are patentable. Third, the current system is inefficient. A large company may spend millions of dollars a year on the “overhead” of patent litigation and prosecution, while a small company may be deterred entirely from the market due to these expenses. Finally, the current system allows inventions to be patented that an owner has no intention of actually using or otherwise making available to the public (e.g., through licensing or dedication to the public). This leads to patent stockpiling, which harms rather than helps the social welfare.
 
Added:
>
>
While the issue described above are each serious flaws of the current patent system, many current proposals fail to address these issues entirely, and instead focus only on small-scale solutions to less serious problems (e.g., tweaking "patent-term" or limiting the number of continuing applications that can be filed).
 
Deleted:
<
<

I. Technical Innovation Improves Social Welfare

 
Deleted:
<
<
  • Insert an edited version of the first paragraph from my first draft of this essay here
 
Changed:
<
<

II. The Trade-Off Between Private and Public IP Rights

>
>

IV. Platform-Based Innovation

 
Changed:
<
<
  • In encouraging technical innovation, there is a trade-off between private and public IP rights
  • Create an inventive incentive, but don't unduly rob the citizenry of quick and cheap access (and don't distort the way in which technical innovation is done!)
  • One extreme - such rights should be temporary and highly-limited. For example, private IP rights would last for short period of time, or would be in the form of a large payout from the government to work on a project (i.e., "pseudo rights")
  • The other extreme - rights should be all but absolute. Long or infinite rights, little government intervention, etc.
  • Virtually everyone agrees that maximizing technical innovation requires some degree of private ownership rights (or incentives that are equivalent to private rights - "pseudo rights" and profitability), but the appropriate degree of rights is highly contentious (for example, Eben believes that such rights should be a very small fraction of what they are today)
  • The patent system is an attempt to strike the right balance between private rights and public rights
>
>
In order to address each of the serious flaws described in Section 3, the current patent system should be tweaked to distinguish between "platform" technology, which should be patentable, and mere "incremental" innovation, which should not be. Further, the current patent system should be changed to allow the government to buy any patented technology, at fair market value, as long as it is doing so for the public good. Under this policy, each of the major pitfalls described above would be remedied.
 
Changed:
<
<

III. The Patent Office

>
>
First, the proposed policy would inherently minimize the patenting of the incremental technology that would have been developed even in the absence of private IP rights. History has shown that when technical platforms are widely available (e.g., computer software), incremental innovation happens automatically through natural human curiosity and experimentation. Second, the proposed policy would encourage long-term research and development that would lead to fundamental new “platform” technologies, which would have the largest impact on social welfare, while discouraging the expenditure of limited resources on only “incremental” innovation. Third, the proposed policy would reduce the overhead costs of obtaining and protecting patent rights. This is because fewer patent applications would be filed, and because those few patents that are granted would be sufficiently different from each other to avoid the confusion and ambiguity, fewer false patent infringement lawsuits would also be filed. Finally, the takings provision ensures that those few patents that are granted cannot be stockpiled and offered to the public at ransom prices. The government would always have the option of buying patented technology at fair market value and dedicating it to the public.
 
Deleted:
<
<
  • The patent system fails to find the sweet spot in private IP rights
    • 20 years - no matter what. Highly suboptimal
  • The patent system distorts the process innovation
    • resources that could go to R&D are diverted to patent litigation and prosecution
    • resources that could go to long-term and fundamental innovation (which is often unpatentable) are diverted instead to short-term ideas that are patentable
  • Leads to stockpiling without intention to use
  • Inhibits sharing and collaboration
  • While the above issues are certainly sub-optimalities, many current proposals (e.g., adjusting "patent-term") amount to small-scale solutions for a large-scale problem
 
Deleted:
<
<

IV. The Sweet Spot - Platform-Based Innovation

 
Deleted:
<
<
  • A more appropriate way to slice private and public IP rights would be to distinguish between "platform" technology, which should be patentable (though subject to mandatory "takings" by the gov't) and "incremental" innovation, which should not be patentable.
  • in technical areas where the platforms are widely available (e.g., computer software), the "incremental" innovation happens automatically through natural human curiosity and experimentation - there is little or no need to provide private IP rights
  • but building platforms are typically resource intensive and require the profit-motive (e.g., the cellular network, etc.)
  • therefore, the gov't should grant private IP rights so as to create platforms, but then buy out these platforms and make them available to the public
  • there is no need to grant private IP rights to encourage "incremental" innovation
 
Changed:
<
<

V. A Proposed Implementation

  • This is a fairly drastic call for change, and will not be adopted overnight (see Section VI for sources of resistance)
  • The practical way to bring about change - implement change through the Section 103 non-obviousness requirement of the current patent system to better capture the trade-off between private and public IP rights
    • i.e., by reinterpreting Section 103, "platform"-based innovation can be deemed non-obvious (and therefore patentable), while "incremental" innovation can be deemed obvious (and therefore unpatentable)
  • Although a ground up approach would be better - not as realistic at the current time
>
>

V. Implementing Platform-Based Innovation

 
Deleted:
<
<

VI. Anticipated Consequences and Sources of Resistance

 
Changed:
<
<
  • Many, many, fewer patents would issue - less revenue for the USPTO
    • Where does the money collected by the PTO currently go? is it funneled to the general US treasury?
      • if so, there is likely to be much resistance...
  • Who decides what is a "technical platform" for the purposes of granting a patent?
  • Source of corruption - who decides what platforms the government is willing to buy out? How do we determine just compensation? (not as clear as with real-property based takings)
>
>
There is at least one relatively practical way to bring about such change. The proposed policy can be implemented under the 35 U.S.C. § 103 non-obviousness requirement of the current patent system. That is, the PTO could take the position that only "platform" based innovations are “non-obvious” in the sense of 35 U.S.C. § 103, while "incremental" innovations are always “obvious.”
 
Added:
>
>

VI. Sources of Resistance and Corruption

 
Added:
>
>
If the current proposal is adopted, many, many, fewer patents would issue, and these would mean less revenue for the PTO. There would likely be resistance to this idea, as Congress is fond of diverting PTO user fees for general use [5]. Further, there would be a scaling down of the multi-billion dollars enterprise that is the PTO [6].
 
Added:
>
>
Further, there are many sources of corruption to be considered. First, it is not clear who would decide what is a "technical platform" is for the purposes of granting a patent. Further, it is not clear how to determine which innovations the government should buy out, or what just compensation ought to be for a untested innovation that has no established market.
 

VII. Conclusion

Added:
>
>
Patent rights should be recognized only for “platform” technology, and not for mere “incremental” innovation. This revised definition of patentability can be implemented using the current machinery of current patent law under 35 U.S.C. § 103. Although the proposed policy would dramatically reduce the overall amount of private IP rights awarded to citizens and organizations for their inventions, it would likely encourage the actual kinds of innovation that increases societal welfare, while also avoiding many of the negative side effects of the current patent system.
 
Changed:
<
<
-- By SaswatMisra - 23 May 2010
>
>
-- By SaswatMisra - 12 June 2010

Revision 14r14 - 13 Jun 2010 - 01:09:23 - SaswatMisra
Revision 13r13 - 23 May 2010 - 15:40:53 - SaswatMisra
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform.
All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors.
All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
Syndicate this site RSSATOM